Full text: Assess_Ceta

Research  26 
Foregone tariff revenues 
As 75% of all customs duties collected from the member states are transferred to the EU 
revenue for customs duties amounts to more than 10% of the EU budget. In 2014, total 
customs duties in the EU summed up to around EUR 21.9 billion of which EUR 16.5 billion 
became part of the EU Budget.13 In the case of CETA, the EU Commission (2016) esti-
mates that foregone tariff revenues from Canadian imports into the EU are EUR 158 million 
per year from industrial goods alone. When tariffs on other goods (agricultural and food 
products) are added, the foregone revenue for the EU would increase to around EUR 330 
million per year or EUR 3.3 billion over a implementation period of 10 years (UNCTAD-
TRAINS data, average 2010-2014).  
Even though these results are only a rough calculation, data on potential adjustment costs 
and foregone public revenue are lacking in CETA assessments. These potential downsides 
are even more relevant in the case of marginal benefits as reported for CETA. Again, po-
tential gains range from EUR 4 billion (SIA, 2011) to EUR 12 billion (Joint Study, 2008) after 
an implementation period of up to 10 years. In contrast, adjustment costs on EU labor mar-
kets and foregone tariff revenues would sum up to more than EUR 5.5 billion during the 
same time period.  
4.  ALTERNATIVE SIMULATION RESULTS WITH THE ÖFSE GLOBAL 
TRADE MODEL 
In this part, a new assessment of the economic costs and benefits to Canada and the EU 
based on the ÖFSE Global Trade Model, a structuralist CGE Model, is provided. The dis-
tinct difference of our model to standard CGE models is the macroeconomic causality we 
apply. In our model, output and income are determined by aggregate demand. Another cen-
tral feature of the model is that labor market clearance is not required. Therefore, the labor 
market features unemployment. The pricing power of firms is included as output prices are 
mark-ups on nominal unit labor costs. Also distributional aspects are considered by way of 
including a wage bargaining process. However, changes in imports and exports are func-
tions of relative prices and demand, in standard fashion. Thus, as in standard CGE models, 
imports react to changes in trade costs via tariff reductions and NTM alignments (see Raza 
et al. (2016b) for details). 
In the following, we briefly discuss the database, model calibration and policy scenarios. In 
subsequent sections, we present simulation results for four scenarios, discuss the possibil-
ity of economic adjustment costs in the transition to the post-liberalization equilibrium, and 
document various exercises on sensitivity analysis, so as to contextualize results.  
4.1. Aggregation, calibration and scenarios  
The database is disaggregated into eleven countries and regions, and twenty sectors. The 
eleven regions are five EU countries – Germany, France, Italy, Austria and UK – and two 
sub-regions, Northern Europe (NE) and Southern & Eastern Europe (SEE). Canada and the 
US are two further individual countries. Remaining countries are disaggregated into “other 
OECD” and the rest of the world (ROW). In total, 20 sectors per country/region are included 
with sectoral breakdowns defined by GTAP (all details included in Table A in the Annex). 
                                                        
13   
Source: http://ec.europa.eu/taxation_customs/customs/policy_issues/facts_and_figures/customs_mean_revenue_en.htm 
 (01/06/2016)
        

Note to user

Dear user,

In response to current developments in the web technology used by the Goobi viewer, the software no longer supports your browser.

Please use one of the following browsers to display this page correctly.

Thank you.